Column for week of November 10, 2014 We have considered how everyone's goal is to maximize their satisfaction. Also we have observed that individuals won't change the choices they make unless we block their chosen road to satisfaction, or they find what they believe is a better road. Our consideration also included some of the ways individuals can try to influence others in their pursuit of satisfaction. We will now consider trading satisfactions. Last time Fred was trying to influence Erwin to refrain from eating a candy bar. We saw that merely arguing or debating with Erwin could easily fail to influence him to refrain from eating the candy. Does Fred have another string on his bow? Fred might try to make an offer Erwin couldn't resist. Suppose Fred offered Erwin a new car in exchange for the candy bar. What are the chances that Erwin would pass up the satisfaction from a new car for the satisfaction of eating the candy? You might ask, Why would Fred offer a car for a candy bar? Whether he would or not isn't important. As in the old joke, we have established that Erwin has a price. At most we now quibble over how low that price will go. Some reward of alternate satisfaction will be enough to get Erwin to give up the candy bar. As the saying goes, everyone has a price. That price may not be measured in dollars. Yet, there are few satisfactions that individuals will not give up for the right exchange. The robber's victim gives up his money for his life. Most of our exchanges aren't that extreme. Yet, we endlessly give up one satisfaction for another. We trade free time and effort for wages. Those money wages aren't what we want. We want the satisfaction we hope to gain from the things we trade the wages for. The money wages are only coupons we hope to exchange for satisfying things. By offering trades we constantly influence others to give up a lesser satisfaction for a greater one. The merchant gives up the satisfaction offered by a loaf of bread because he expects to gain more satisfaction from the two dollars he receives. At the same time, the buyer expects more satisfaction from the bread. In fact, he expects more satisfaction from the bread than from any other thing he could buy with the two dollars. If something else promised more satisfaction, he would buy it instead of the bread. We also trade satisfactions over time. He who saves the candy bar to eat tomorrow instead of now believes he will gain more satisfaction by doing it. The person who saves to spend later is trying to trade present satisfaction for future satisfaction. The ways we trade lesser satisfactions for greater ones are almost endless. Rewards have so much potential for increasing satisfaction that they should be our first resort when trying to influence the choices of others. Unfortunately many turn first to the force of government. Exchange and rewards create winners. Government's use of force and threats creates victims and losers. The victims are coerced into reduced satisfaction. Someone has to pay for the coercion. The effort spent on coercion produces no value except for the person who gains satisfaction from dominating others. The person coerced to give up a satisfaction to satisfy someone else sacrifices his satisfaction to satisfy the other person. The one coerced is partially enslaved by the one he is coerced to serve. If total slavery is wrong and bad, How can partial slavery be right and good? Next time: What happens when free people trade satisfactions? aldmccallum@gmail.com * * * * * * * * * * * * * * * Copyright 2014 Albert D. McCallum
Considering the issues of our times. (ADM does not select or endorse the sites reached through "Next Blog.")
Thursday, November 20, 2014
Trading for Satisfaction
Monday, November 10, 2014
Persuading Others
Column for week of November 3, 2014 In prior columns we have considered that everyone always makes the choices they believe will be the most satisfying. We also considered forcible obstruction and punishment as ways to prevent or discourage others from making the choices they believe will bring the most satisfaction. Now we will consider using persuasion to influence others to alter their choices. Back to the candy bar example. Suppose Erwin is about to eat his candy bar. Fred wants to persuade Erwin to refrain from eating the candy. There is only one way Fred can succeed. He must convince Erwin that he will gain more satisfaction from refraining from eating the candy bar than from eating it now. Fred might convince Erwin that he will gain the most satisfaction from giving away or destroying the candy bar. Perhaps Fred only convinces Erwin that he can increase his satisfaction by postponing eating the candy. If Fred's goal is to stop Erwin from eating the candy bar, the latter result buys Fred more time to pursue his goal. If Erwin still believes the most satisfying thing he can do is eat the candy now, he will start chewing. We might give a thought or two to why Fred wants to keep Erwin from eating the candy. The bottom line is that Fred expects to gain satisfaction from persuading Erwin to refrain from eating the candy bar. Not only that, Fred also believes that in his present circumstances the most satisfying thing Fred can do is try to persuade Erwin to not eat the candy. If Fred believed he had an option that would bring him more satisfaction, he would forget about Erwin and the candy to pursue the more satisfying option. How might Fred gain satisfaction from keeping Erwin from eating the candy? Perhaps Fred believes candy will be bad for Erwin. Fred might gain satisfaction from doing a good deed. Possibly Fred hopes to get the candy from Erwin. Fred might gain satisfaction merely from convincing Erwin not to eat the candy. The possibilities are nearly endless. Only Fred could know the real reason. He might not be honest enough with himself to even recognize his real motivation. Fred could make a serious and honest argument to Erwin. Also, Fred could make an emotional appeal. Outright lying and fraud are other possibilities. The bottom line is that Fred must somehow influence Erwin to expect more satisfaction from passing up the candy than from eating it. What really happens to Erwin's satisfaction in the long run is irrelevant to the choice Erwin will make. He has only his expectations to guide him when he chooses. The consequence of the choice may influence future choices and Erwin's confidence in Fred. Trying to influence the choices of anyone for any reason is subject to all of the same limitations and pit falls. It generally isn't easy to convince most people to change their expectations about satisfaction. Often people don't even try using persuasion to influence others' choices about what is satisfying. Instead, they cry out "there ought to be a law." Saying there ought to be a law is usually an appeal to force, violence and threats thereof. A law is merely an order from government that is meaningless if not backed by the threat of forcibly decreasing the satisfaction of the violator. The law could offer a reward for certain changes, such as a bounty for killing foxes. An individual could offer the reward without any law. When someone appeals to government to offer a reward they are asking government to use force to collect the money to pay the reward. So far in our search for ways to influence others in the choices they make while pursuing satisfaction, we haven't found anything that promises great success. Next time: Trading for satisfaction. aldmccallum@gmail.com * * * * * * * * * * * * * * * Copyright 2014 Albert D. McCallum
Thursday, November 6, 2014
Influencing the Choices of Others With Force
Column for week of October 27, 2014 Last time we saw that the ultimate goal of every person is to maximize satisfaction. Things and activities aren't the ultimate goals of anyone. We only seek the satisfaction we hope to gain through things and activities. If we want to influence the choices of others we must physically limit their choices, or get the individual to alter his views at to what is satisfying. Today we will consider only the use of force to alter choices. When I was a child my mother tried various ways to physically limit my choices. When she went shopping in Muskegon she first confined me in a buggy. When I grew she turned to a harness and a tether that she held. Both were reasonably effective in limiting my choices. At home if she frowned on what I was doing she sometimes tied me in a chair. This limit was imperfect. I could still choose to tip the chair over. Imprisoning individuals is a way of limiting their choices. Killing is the ultimate limit on choices. It eliminates the individual's option of making choices we don't like. It also eliminates all other choices. Imprisonment isn't totally effective in limiting the choices we consider undesirable. Inmates still do things that their captors don't like. The problem is that mere imprisonment usually doesn't change the prisoner's views of what he believes will be satisfying. Another way of changing the individual's view of what will be satisfying is to eliminate the anticipated satisfaction. Altering an individual so that drinking alcohol will make him sick immediately is likely to discourage him from seeking satisfaction from drinking. Beating or imprisoning a thief may take the satisfaction out of theft. Of course, if the thief rightly, or wrongly, believes he can avoid the beating or imprisonment next time, the past punishment will not influence him to quit stealing. Punishment doesn't do much to alter the future choices of the dumb or short sighted who choose to steal without considering the possible consequence. Neither does it limit the choices of those who believe they are clever enough to get away with it next time. Force can also be used to alter the choices of individuals who have done nothing wrong. The threats of an armed robber may alter the victim's views of the net satisfaction he is likely to get from trying to keep his money. The victim many conclude that he will gain more satisfaction from staying alive and healthy than from fighting to keep his money. None of the uses of force are likely to alter the individual's basic beliefs about what he will find satisfying. Remove the threat of force and the individual will most likely revert to making the same choices as before. Consider immigration. If we could totally seal the borders so no one could cross, immigration would end. We can't do that or even come close, no matter how many fences we build. The next line of defense is to inflict dissatisfaction on illegal immigrants. How much dissatisfaction must we inflict to discourage a would be immigrant who faces mainly misery and starvation at home? What are the chances he won't still see illegal entry as a way to increase his satisfaction? Force, either for blocking choices or punishing them, isn't very effective at stopping individuals from making choices we don't like. One of the reasons people so quickly resort to the force option is that many among us gain satisfaction from using force to control others. These people are control freaks. They control others not so much for altering the choices of others as for the satisfaction gained from controlling others. Not surprisingly these individuals are likely to migrate to government. Government, and those specially privileged by it, are the only ones who may legally use aggressive force. More about this later. Next time: Persuasion as a way to alter the choices of others. aldmccallum@gmail.com * * * * * * * * * * * * * * * Copyright 2014 Albert D. McCallum
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)